“It is usual to reckon the acceptance of a deposit which can be drawn upon at any time by means of notes or cheques as a type of credit transaction and juristically this view is, of course, justified; but economically, the case is not one of a credit transaction. If credit in the economic sense means the exchange of a present good or a present service against a future good or a future service, then it is hardly possible to include the transactions in question under the conception of credit. A depositor of a sum of money who acquires in exchange for it a claim convertible into money at any time which will perform exactly the same service for him as the sum it refers to has exchanged no present good for a future good. The claim that he has acquired by his deposit is also a present good for him. The depositing of the money in no way means that he has renounced immediate disposal over the utility it commands.” (Mises 2009: 269; see also Huerta de Soto 2006: 14–15; Rothbard 2011: 733–734; cf. Rozeff 2010).Essentially, this reduces to the question whether the FR account (or even callable loan) constitutes “the exchange of a present good or a present service against a future good or a future service.” The Austrian argument assumes that money is a good (Huerta de Soto 2006: 696), and with respect to any commodity money system that assumption can be accepted, when money proper in the sense of the commodity money base is distinguished from debt instruments used as a medium of exchange. In a fiat money system, money as the final means of payment is the fiat base money, the obligations of the central bank, and in fiat money systems one will have to say that the FR account involves the exchange of present units of account/medium of exchange for future goods (considered as banking services) and units of account/medium of exchange.
The FR reserve account is an exchange of present for future goods (or exchange of present units of account/medium of exchange for future goods and units of account/medium of exchange), for the following reasons:
(1) you give up the ownership and possession of your money (the present good) in exchange forIt is clear that the argument for the FR reserve account constituting an exchange of present for future goods relies on the crucial point that the FR clients do in fact give up the ownership of their money.
(2) the future goods that are (a) interest (which will be paid at a certain future date) and/or (b) banking services (e.g., the use of cheques, debit cards, electronic funds transfer, etc.), and (c) repayment of your loan as recorded in the debt instrument you receive, your FR account.
Now how do we know that the FR bank clients do, in actual fact, give up the ownership of their money? The reason is that we have overwhelming empirical evidence: we can look carefully at the present and historical actual actions and practices of FR clients and bankers, their free exchanges, their contracts, how both parties understand these actions and contracts, and how these practices were understood in human legal systems.
Let us review the two pieces of evidence:
(1) Real World Contracts, Exchange and Banking Practice.The free actions, actual real world contracts, practices and law relating to FR accounts demonstrate that callable mutuum loans involve the transfer of ownership of the money lent.
First, the voluntary and free contract entered into to by two parties that we call the fractional reserve bank account was a real world banking practice, specified by written and verbal agreement.
In Roman law, there were a number of types of real contract (contracts re), as follows:(1) mutuum (loan for consumption);In Roman law, the mutuum contract included loans repayable on demand (loans with a call option, as it were), and the explicit evidence for this can be found in the Institutes of Gaius (161 AD):
(2) commodatum (loan for use);
(3) pignus (pledge), and
(4) depositum or depositum regulare (bailment for safe keeping).“The agreement enforceable as mutuum could only be for the restoration of an equal sum of money or of goods equal in quantity and similar in quality to those lent, at a date named or, if no date was named, on demand.” (De Zulueta 1953: 149).Already under Roman civil law, the mutuum loan of money involves either (1) a time deposit or (2) a demand deposit/callable loan. Because money can be regarded as representing a certain value, what is deposited is a quantity of a thing (quantitas) and not an individual thing itself (corpus). The depositor thus receives back the same quantity (tantundem) of money, not the same money itself (Zimmermann 1990: 215–216). The essence of the mutuum contract is that ownership rights to the money pass from the creditor to debtor: in the case of a FR account the bank now became the owner of the money.
Therefore the mutuum was the legal framework and concept under which fractional reserve banking was conducted in ancient Rome (Zimmermann 1990: 218). Whether the mutuum was a time deposit or a demand deposit depended on the type of contract between the two parties, and there is no reason to think that fractional reserve banking was held as either immoral or illegal (for how Roman law influenced Medieval law on banking, see Dotson 2004: 89–92). The evidence for the existence of FRB in the Roman Republic and Roman Empire is overwhelming (Harris 2006: 11; Harris 2011: 236). There is not one shred of evidence that it was regarded as immoral or prosecuted as a crime.
There was even a clear action and convention by which two parties indicated that their entering into such an mutuum exchange: in actual banking practice for over 2,000 years, since the Roman Republic, two parties have engaged in a type of callable loan called in Latin the mutuum, by which money brought to a bank was determined to be a loan if it was handed over in an unsealed box/bag/container.
In the Middle ages, these conventions continued. The practice of giving over money in an unsealed bag or box, as described above, was recognised in Talmudic law (Goldin 1913: 68), as it was from the Jewish community from which many medieval bankers came.
The convention entered European civil law, and it was still cited by American judges in the 19th century in Dawson et al vs. the Real Estate Bank before the Supreme Court of Arkansas in 1845:“From a careful consideration of the authorities on this subject, we understand the general rule to be, that where money, not in a sealed packet, or closed box, bag or chest, is deposited with a bank or banking corporation, the law presumes it to be a general deposit [= mutuum loan – LK], until the contrary appears; because such deposit is esteemed the most advantageous to the depositary, and most consistent with the general objects, usages, and course of business of such companies or corporations. But if the deposit be made of any thing sealed or locked up or otherwise covered or secured in a package, cask, box, bag or chest, or any thing of the like kind of or belonging to the depositor, the law regards it as a pure or special deposit [= bailment – LK], and the depositary as having the custody thereof only for safe keeping, and the accommodation of the depositor.” (Pike 1845: 296–297).The “general deposit” is a mutuum (or loan) and the “pure or special deposit” refers to a depositum (or bailment). The tradition of sealing money in a bag, chest or box to indicate that it was to be held in safekeeping as a depositum (not as a mutuum) goes right back to English banking practices that have been examined by Selgin (2011). In English law, showing the influence of Roman law through the Norman conquest, certainly from Elizabethan times, and probably from the Norman conquest, law and banking practice distinguished the bailment (depositum) deposit of money from the mutuum loan of money. The question whether the mutuum was a FR account (or callable loan) or time deposit would depend on the type of verbal or written contract or whether it was handed over in a sealed bag or not. This is how freely consenting clients and bankers understood their fractional reserve accounts/loans, in real world actions.
So the free actions and contractual understanding of agents engaged in FR mutuum loans throughout history
(2) The Evidence of Law.
In the legal systems, codes and legal treatises of European civilisation for over 2,000 years that described banking practice, the exchanges I have discussed above are clearly recognised. In the 4th edition of A New Institute of the Imperial or Civil Law (1730; 1st edn. 1704), Thomas Wood (1661–1722), the English Doctor of Civil Law (New College, Oxford), defines the mutuum contract:“Mutuum (a Loan simply so call’d quod de meo tuum fiat [sc. “because let what is mine become yours”])First, the transfer of ownership of the money in a mutuum loan is explicitly stated by Wood above in the Latin phrase de meo tuum fiat (“let what is mine become yours”). This phrase (in the form quod de meo tuum fit) goes right back to Roman law (MacLeod 1902: 149) as a way of describing the mutuum loan, and is found as a definition of mutuum in the Digest (at 12.1.2.2) of Justinian (AD 530-533), part of that emperor’s Corpus Iuris Civilis (Body of Civil Law). Secondly, Wood’s statement here is important:
It hath no one particular name in the English Language.
is a Contract introduced by the Law of Nations, in which a Thing that consists in weight (as Bullion,) in number (as Money,) in measure (as Wine,) “is given to another upon condition that he shall return another thing of the same Quantity, Nature and Value upon demand. More than Consent is required, for the Thing, viz. Money, Wine, or Oil ought to be actually delivered, and more than what was delivered cannot be repaid; but less may be repaid by Agreement. This Contract forces men to be industrious and promotes Trade, and for this reason it may be greater charity to lend than to give. Creditum is a more general Word. In the case of Money, Silver may be repaid tor Gold, unless the Creditor is to be damnified by it; for it shall be understood to be the same kind of Money when it is of the same” (Wood 1730: 212).“he shall return another thing of the same Quantity, Nature and Value upon demand”.The words “upon demand” confirm that under English law mutuum contracts allow demand deposits or what I call FR accounts (and not just time deposits).
If we turn to modern English law, we can cite the The Laws of England: Being a Complete Statement of the Whole Law of England (vol. 2; 3rd edn.; 1964):“The contract of mutuum differs from that of commodatum, in that in the latter a bare possession of the chattel lent, as distinguished from the property in it, vests in the borrower, the general property in it still remaining in the lender; where in mutuum that property in the chattel passes from the lender to the borrower.This clearly entails that in the case of a mutuum demand deposit in a fractional reserve bank:
Mutuum is confined to such chattels as are intended to be consumed in the using and are capable of being estimated by number, weight, or measure, such as money, corn, or wine. The essence of the contract in the case of such loans is, not that the borrower should return to the lender the identical chattels lent (for such specific return would ordinarily render the loan valueless), but that upon demand or at a fixed date the lender should receive from the borrower an equivalent quantity of the chattels lent.” (Halsbury 1964: 112).(1) Ownership of the money passes from the client to the fractional reserve bank;When a modern fractional reserve bank takes money for a new deposit, this is actually a personal loan to the bank. The money in the deposit becomes the property of the bank. This is clearly stated in FR contracts and in modern law. That fact underlies the conclusion that FR banking is an exchange of present for future goods.
(2) The bank returns only money up to the same value (a tantundem), not the original money;
(3) By the terms of the mutuum contract, the money can be returned either at a fixed future date or on demand.
The typical Austrian advocate of a priori praxeology is incapable of refuting the overwhelming evidence that people have in fact historically freely contracted to give up ownership of their money and enter into a debt contract in the case of FR accounts and callable loans. This how the FR current account/transactions account is properly defined today. The only solution that such Austrian cultists are driven to is the absurd denial of the relevance of the empirical evidence of the FR contract terms, actual banking practice, real world FR exchanges, and the principles defined in law. Such a denial is essentially an admission of defeat in argument.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Dotson, John E. 2004. “Banks and Banking,” in C. Kleinhenz (ed.), Medieval Italy: An Encyclopedia. Vol. 1, A to K, Routledge, London. 89–92.
Goldin, H. E. 1913. Mishnah. A Digest of the Basic Principles of the Early Jewish Jurisprudence, Baba Meziah (Middle Gate), Order IV, Treatise II, G. P. Putnam’s Sons, New York & London.
Halsbury, H. S. G. 1964. The Laws of England: Being a Complete Statement of the Whole Law of England (vol. 2; 3rd edn.; ed. G. T. Simonds), Butterworth, London.
Harris, W. V. 2006. “A Revisionist View of Roman Money,” Journal of Roman Studies 96: 1–24.
Harris, W. V. 2011. Rome’s Imperial Economy. Twelve Essays, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Huerta de Soto, J. 2006. Money, Bank Credit and Economic Cycles (trans. M. A. Stroup), Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Ala
Macleod, Henry Dunning, 1893. The Theory and Practice of Banking in Two Volumes (2nd edn.; vol. 1), Longmans, Green and Co., London.
Mises, L. von, 2009 [1953]. The Theory of Money and Credit (trans. J. E. Batson), Mises Institute, Auburn, Ala.
Rothbard, M. N. 2009. Man, Economy, and State: A Treatise on Economic Principles (2nd edn.), Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, Ala.
Rozeff, M. S. 2010. “Rothbard on Fractional Reserve Banking: A Critique,” Independent Review 14.4 (Spring): 497–512.
Selgin, G. “Those Dishonest Goldsmiths,” revised January 20, 2011
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1589709
Wood, Thomas. 1730. A New Institute of the Imperial or Civil Law (4th edn.), J. and J. Knapton, London.
Zimmermann, R. 1990. The Law of Obligations: Roman Foundations of the Civilian Tradition, Juta & Co, Cape Town.
Zulueta, Francis de. 1953. The Institutes of Gaius Part 2, Clarendon Press, Oxford.
I don't deny at ALL that contracts can be made legally where people give up ownership of their present money for future money (+ interest)/services. But, the crucial point is that the public and the economy perceives and treats the money that they have "loaned out" but still have a claim that the bank may or may not contractually have to honor as present money. To deny this is ridiculous. Legal historians and economists can debate this stuff day and night, but what matters is the everyday public.
ReplyDeleteAsk anyone on the street and ask them whether or not they have loaned out the money in their banking accounts or keep it on demand. Despite what they have signed off on the contract, they will 99% tell you that they either 1)Think the bank has the money in the vault or 2)know that the bank has "loaned out" so of their "money", but they still have some sort of "claim" to this money. So, in essence, they perceive that they have claims to present money, whether or not this is legally the case. (THIS IS NOT SAYING FRB IS FRAUD OR ISSUES MULTIPLE "MONEY TITLES", BUT THAT THE PUBLIC JUST PERCEIVES (crucial!!) THEM AS MONEY TITLES)
Everyday transactions are based on this assumption. When I buy a pack of cigarettes, the price is $X dollars. So when I hand the cashier my debit card he assumes that he will have a claim of some sort of "present money" on the "money" that goes into his bank account.
Whether or not they contractually give up money is besides the point, which can be perfectly fine in legal settings. What matters is that with a callable loan checking account, they perceive that they still have access to funds, and present money.
(I'm a little disappointed that you didn't post my other response, btw).
Ask anyone on the street and ask them whether or not they have loaned out the money in their banking accounts or keep it on demand. Despite what they have signed off on the contract, they will 99% tell you that they either 1)Think the bank has the money in the vault or 2)know that the bank has "loaned out" so of their "money", but they still have some sort of "claim" to this money.
ReplyDeleteThat is a quite separate issue:
http://socialdemocracy21stcentury.blogspot.com/2011/12/are-public-ignorant-of-nature-of.html
"Everyday transactions are based on this assumption. When I buy a pack of cigarettes, the price is $X dollars. So when I hand the cashier my debit card he assumes that he will have a claim of some sort of "present money" on the "money" that goes into his bank account. "
ReplyDeleteHe does: when the bank settles/clears its accounts with other banks money in the sense of the final unit of account is transferred.
"What matters is that with a callable loan checking account, they perceive that they still have access to funds, and present money."
ReplyDeleteThe mistaken perception does not refute the fact that, economically speaking, it is recalling a debt, the future good is the money repaid.
Anyway, the whole point of the Mises quote and the Austrian objection to FRB is that, economically speaking, they think it is not an exchange of a present for future good, even if people were to think so. That argument, however, is unsound.
If some percentage of the public (say, 40%-60%) mistakenly sees it as a bailment that does not change is real economic nature as a credit transaction.
Legally speaking, it is a debt. Economically speaking, they act as if they still have access to the funds. Its a "credit transaction", but at the same time the public doesn't perceive it as that. Not saying that this is a contractual violation, but economically/socially thats just how it is.
ReplyDelete(We can just continue this in other thread)
Lord Keynes:
ReplyDelete"The FR reserve account is an exchange of present for future goods (or exchange of present units of account/medium of exchange for future goods and units of account/medium of exchange), for the following reasons:"
"(1) you give up the ownership and possession of your money (the present good) in exchange for"
"(2) the future goods that are (a) interest (which will be paid at a certain future date) and/or (b) banking services (e.g., the use of cheques, debit cards, electronic funds transfer, etc.), and (c) repayment of your loan as recorded in the debt instrument you receive, your FR account."
(a) is not a proper justification for the claim that FR accounts are economically future goods. The very low "interest" on FR accounts was developed as a means to make it appear as if FR accounts are future goods, so that they can then appear as if they are loans in the economic sense. If no "interest" on such accounts was given, then are you saying the absence of such "interest" would turn these accounts into present goods and not loans? Of course not.
Historically, "mutuum" accounts didn't always accrue interest, and even today, not all demand deposit accounts at all banks accrue interest.
(b) "banking services" are economically identical to "interest". They are not a proper justification for the claim that FR accounts are future goods. They are only to attract clients into depositing their money with that bank, as opposed to some other bank. The bank can afford these additional services because they charge a rate of interest on the demand deposit money that was given to them, which they loan out. As with "interest", historically it is also the case that additional banking services weren't always offered to demand depositors. Moreover, the introduction of "perks" for demand deposit clients also does not change the economic nature of the demand deposit in the context of arguing over present versus future goods.
If my friend allowed me to keep my car in his garage while my house is renovated, and my car is so nice that he positively values my car just being there, such that he collects my mail while I am away, or gives me $20 just because, then no matter what he does for me, it doesn't change the economic nature of the context of determining whether the car is a present good or a future good. It remains a present good because I can take possession of it any time I want. What he does in addition to providing his garage to store my car, whether he offered it to me in return for keeping my car in his garage, or offered it to me after we already agreed, is actually completely irrelevant.
(c) is again just begging the question, because the question of whether or not the deposit is a loan in the economic sense is the thing that is being argued over. By merely defining it as a loan, as a premise for your conclusion that it is a loan, that is begging the question. It would be like me arguing that the FR account is not a loan, but a present good for the client, by using the premise that satisfying a demand withdrawal request is just a payment of what is economically a non-loan and a present good in control of the client. I would also be begging the question because that premise is the conclusion that is being debated.
"The very low "interest" on FR accounts was developed as a means to make it appear as if FR accounts are future goods, so that they can then appear as if they are loans in the economic sense. "
ReplyDeleteOh, really! The conspiracy theory view of history!
"Historically, "mutuum" accounts didn't always accrue interest"
ReplyDeleteNosense. Interest was regularly paid on mutuum loans payable on demand in ancient Rome, and historically, FR accounts were paying interest from the 1600s in the UK.
Selgin, G. “Those Dishonest Goldsmiths,” revised January 20, 2011, p. 7
http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1589709
"it doesn't change the economic nature of the context of determining whether the car is a present good or a future good. It remains a present good because I can take possession of it any time I want."
ReplyDeleteSo the issue of the FR account as a future good comes down to whether ownership is actually transferred and whether (because of that) it is a loan - the empirical and legal evidence shows overwhelming that it is trasnferred and it is a loan.
"(c) is again just begging the question, because the question of whether or not the deposit is a loan in the economic sense is the thing that is being argued over."
ReplyDeleteSo even if
(1) one party hands over money to a banker and both explicitly agree that the ownership of their money passes to the banker;
(2) the bank gives the client a credit/debt instrument or an IOU redeemable on demand to return to them money up to the amount in his/her account from (a) the bank’s reserves, (b) from sale of financial assets, or (3) loans.
(3) it is understood by all parties that most of the original money has been loaned out (except for that portion held as reserves which is now the bank's property), and only a tantundem from the bank’s reserves, money from sale of financial assets, or loans is provided.
----
Is this a loan in the sense that the property rights have passed to the bank or not?
"The very low "interest" on FR accounts was developed as a means to make it appear as if FR accounts are future goods, so that they can then appear as if they are loans in the economic sense. If no "interest" on such accounts was given, then are you saying the absence of such "interest" would turn these accounts into present goods and not loans?"
ReplyDeleteNo. Because the primary future good is the repayment of money on demand from your debt called in from the bank.
You gave up property rights in the money you lent. You gave up a present good when you lent the original money. Even without interest and banking services, this would still be a loan contract that is the exchnage of a present for a future good.