We can see the size of the deficit in the graph below (with data from Eichengreen 1995: 138, Table 5.1).
As we can see, the deficit of 1919 was large (larger than that of 1923, the worst year of the hyperinflation), but from 1920 to 1922 – apart from a small rise in 1921 – there was a clear falling trend. This was caused by the recovery of the German economy and by the tax reform of Matthias Erzberger passed in 1919. The falling deficit was actually a cause of increased confidence in the German economy at the time.
If the large deficits were the primary cause of the hyperinflation, then one must wonder why hyperinflation did not occur earlier in 1919 or 1920.
For the historical reality is that, although from the end of the First World War until early 1920, there was a serious depreciation of the mark, a degree of stability and confidence returned in 1920:
“This [sc. crisis of confidence] came to a halt in the spring of 1920 as conflict between domestic political factions diminished, increasing imports improved living conditions, industrial production began to grow and, in March 1920, the Erzberger tax reforms were enacted. ‘[I]t seemed that a certain faith in the mark was again established among the German population.’ Confidence and optimistic expectations about the future value of the mark remained dominant until the London Ultimatum of May 1921. Prices remained broadly stable, despite the continued growth of the nominal quantity of money… .” (Holtfrerich 1986: 190).Given the falling deficit, the tax reform, the prospects for budget balancing, and the hope that the final reparations burden would be more realistic than the initial proposed figure, the evidence would suggest that there really were grounds for confidence in the mark from 1920 to May 1921 (Webb 1989: 54; see also Burdekin and Langdana 1995: 93).
The return of a relative stability in the dollar–paper mark exchange rate in 1920 and early 1921 can be seen in the graph below (with data from Feldman 1993: 5, Table 1).
As we can see, by early 1921 the mark’s value had stabilised in terms of dollars. Then after the May 1921 London Ultimatum the catastrophic depreciation began, which was a fundamental driver of the hyperinflation.
It was only after May 1921 and the currency depreciation that run-away inflation occurred as well, as we can see in the German wholesale price index graph below (with data from Burdekin and Langdana 1995: 108, Table A5.1).
A further really catastrophic shift in domestic expectations about, and confidence in, the mark appears to have happened after June 1922 when the mark lost its role not only as a store of value but also as a unit of account (Holtfrerich 1986: 70), but this is perfectly consistent with the view that it was the accelerating currency depreciation beginning in late 1921 that was the fundamental driver of the hyperinflation.
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Bresciani-Turroni, Costantino. 1937. The Economics of Inflation: A Study of Currency Depreciation in Post-War Germany (trans. Millicent E. Sayers), Allen & Unwin, London.
Burdekin, Richard C. K. and Farrokh K. Langdana. 1995. Confidence, Credibility, and Macroeconomic Policy: Past, Present, Future. Routledge, London and New York.
Feldman, Gerald D. 1993. The Great Disorder: Politics, Economics, and Society in the German Inflation, 1914–1924. Oxford University Press, New York.
Holtfrerich, Carl-Ludwig. 1986. The German Inflation 1914–1923: Causes and Effects in International Perspective (trans. Theo Balderston). De Gruyter, New York.
Webb, Steven B. 1989. Hyperinflation and Stabilization in Weimar Germany. Oxford University Press, New York.
Do you see government deficits as being inherently inflationary ? Wouldn't the level of monetization of govt debt be more relevant to the growth in the money supply ? Is data available for that ?
ReplyDeleteYes, government deficits tend to be inflationary.
DeleteBut how much depends on circumstances.
Were the Weimar government deficits of 1919 and 1920 sufficient to ignite hyperinflation in those years? Clearly not.
Now that you've explored the data in depth I'm sure you'll agree that there really is only one interpretation of this hyperinflation, right LK?
ReplyDeleteThe irony is that the "Allied view" became ingrained in the Bundesbank after the war (and from there infected the ECB). The reason for this seems to have been partly due to political opportunism -- right-wingers using the hyperinflation myth to push neoliberalism -- but it was in part due to a bizarre rewriting of history that took place after the war in Germany (and, to a lesser extent, in the US).
Hayek was at the center of this as yet untold story. Someone could write a bestseller on this!
http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/2013/01/philip-pilkington-the-origins-of-neoliberalism-part-i-hayeks-delusion.html
Yes, on what was the fundamental cause of the hyperinflation, I agree.
DeleteIt is extremely difficult to blame the deficits of 1919, 1920 or even 1921.
If that were so, then why was the wholesale price index flat right up until the London ultimatum? It makes no sense.