I have to say I doubt whether the “Great Communicator,” who was allegedly showing increasing symptoms of Alzheimer’s in his years as president, ever properly understood the hybrid nature of his administration’s economic policies.
In truth, Reagan’s economic policies were run by his advisers, and by competing factions in his administration, including (1) monetarists, (2) supply-siders, and (3) fiscal conservatives. Different factions had different agendas, and one faction had greater dominance over others at certain times.
The Supply-Siders in the administration were Arthur Laffer, Martin Anderson, and Paul Craig Roberts. They appear to have been supported by Don Regan, Secretary of the Treasury from 1981–1985, and the President to some degree.
David Stockman was a fiscal conservative, who opposed the Supply-Siders on their tax cuts late in 1981 (Roberts 1984: 186–187; 191–192). This opposition was made worse after his interview with the Atlantic Monthly published in December that year (W. Greider, 1981. “The Education of David Stockman,” The Atlantic Online), which appears to have been an attempt to discredit the Supply-Siders (Roberts 1984: 192–193).
In the late 1980s, the outstanding Post Keynesian economist Alfred S. Eichner published a critical article analysing Reaganomics (Eichner 1988: 541–556). I base this post on his analysis.
Eichner divided the neoliberal or conservative economic factions in the Reagan administration into the three groups I mentioned above:
“1. the monetarists, committed to the proposition that limiting the growth of the money supply is the only way to bring inflation under control;Furthermore, the early Reagan administration was characterized by two periods, which Eichner describes as follows:
2. the “supply-siders,” arguing for lower tax rates (and, subsequently, lower interest rates) as the best means of boosting the economy’s long-term growth rate; and
3. the fiscal conservatives, concerned primarily with balancing the federal budget” (Eichner 1988: 544).
“(1) the period from the first quarter of 1981 through the second quarter of 1982, during which the Reagan administration merely pursued with greater vigor policies begun under President Carter, andI think all this is essentially correct.
(2) the period since then, marked by a reversal of the previously restrictive monetary policy and the delayed impact of the radically expansive fiscal policy the Reagan administration succeeded in pushing through Congress shortly after taking office”(Eichner 1988: 543).
Reagan’s economic policies can be divided into the (1) monetarist (or at least quasi-monetarist) period from 1981 to 1982, and (2) the supply-side period from 1982 onwards.
Let’s review these two periods below.
The monetarist period was directed by Paul Volcker from the Fed, and it was actually a continuation of the monetarism that he had begun under Jimmy Carter in 1979. Far from being an innovation of Reagan, the turn to monetarist doctrine was the fault of Carter (or, if you are a conservative, you might say the “credit” would have to go to Carter!).
In 1979–1981, the world experienced the second of the oil shocks, and serious double digit inflation.
Some policy-makers like Thatcher and Carter decided to adopt the elements of Milton Freidman’s monetarist doctrine to control inflation by controlling money supply growth. The essence of this is the belief that “inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon,” and that central bank control of the money stock or its growth rate will control inflation rates, with minimal loss of output growth and minimal unemployment.
But, as Post Keynesians know, it is a myth that the central bank directly controls the broad money stock or its growth rate.
Nevertheless, Paul Volcker attempted a monetarist experiment from 1979–1982, by trying to control the growth rate of M1, through targeting non-borrowed reserves. The orthodox monetarists complain that since Volcker never adopted a constant money growth rule during his experiment in 1979–1982 the period was not really “monetarist.” This is implausible. There is simply no doubt that Volcker’s policy was a departure from normal monetary policy, and that
“… during the 1979–1982 period, the Fed was concerned with money growth and not with fine-tuning real economic activity—behavior we have described as quasi-monetarist” (Hakes and Rose 1992–1993: 286).This quasi-monetarist policy is surely an approximation of a pure monetarist constant money growth rule, and there must be something to be learned from an approximation of an economic theory.
In fact, the lesson we learn is that Volcker’s quasi-monetarism was a miserable failure, with the Fed badly missing its M1 targets (Wray 2003: 92). The Fed simply could not control M1, but this should come as no surprise to advocates of the endogenous money theory.
What actually happened under Volcker is that his “floating” interest rate policy caused the federal funds rate to soar to 19% by June 1981, inducing two severe recessions, the first from January to July 1980, and the second from July 1981 to November 1982. This caused mass unemployment, crippled American manufacturing enterprises in the Midwest, and a Third World debt crisis (Galbraith 2009: 38), as the American recessions and high interest rates essentially caused a global recession (Eichner 1988: 548). The high interest rates in the US also lead to a damaging appreciation of the US dollar late in 1980, which hit US exporters hard (Eichner 1988: 549).
The recessions, the US demand contraction and steep fall in the price of oil (which can be seen in this graph) were the real reason US inflation fell from a peak of 14.8% in March 1980 to 4.6% in November 1982, and not because money supply growth rates were brought under control in the way imagined by monetarism or the quasi-monetarist targeting Volcker pursued.
At this point, I turn to Paul Craig Roberts’s memoir The Supply-Side Revolution (Harvard University Press, 1984). Roberts was a leading supply-side economist, and Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy from early 1981 to January 1982, under the Treasury Secretary Donald Regan.
His account of the monetary policy the Reagan administration had demanded of the Federal Reserve on taking office in 1981 is worth quoting:
“Secretary Regan, Undersecretary Sprinkel, and I are on the public record in testimony before Congress stating that our monetary assumption and the policy we requested from Federal Reserve Chairman Paul Volcker was a gradual 50 percent reduction in the growth rate of the money supply spread over six years. Yet, oddly enough, when I testified before the Senate Budget Committee on March 5, 1982, Chairman Domenici was surprised to hear my statement of the administration’s monetary assumption. He seemed to think that we had supported the very tight monetary policy during 1981, when Volcker collapsed the growth of the money supply to zero for six months of the year….” (Roberts 1984: 115–116).Two points emerge from this. First, Roberts claims that Volcker never implemented the monetary policy that Treasury demanded of him in 1981. Secondly, if the Reagan administration’s stated and intended monetary policy was never implemented, then in no sense can Reaganite apologists claim it was a success. A policy never even implemented cannot even meet the first criterion for judging the success of action, if one’s intended action was never even taken.
“The day after the Reagan inauguration, Treasury was asked to prepare a short memo on the subject of new President’s message to Volcker. The memo read:
There is no way the President can carry out the main points of his administration …. Unless the Federal Reserve provides the right kind of monetary policy. The right policy is stable moderate and predictable money growth … Volker should manage the affairs of the Fed so that uncertainty is reduced … There is no excuse for failure. If the Fed fails, the Reagan Administration fails.
Unfortunately our fears were realized. Instead of evenly spreading the reduction in money growth over a six-year period, the Federal Reserve delivered 75 percent of the reduction in the first year. In November 1981 the Treasury staff reported that the main monetary measure, called M1-B, which consists of currency plus all kinds of checking accounts, had fallen over the previous six months, for only the second time since 1959–60. There was actually less money in the economy in October than there had been the previous April. The growth in M1-B over the year was meagre, roughly equivalent to figures for the recession years of 1970 to 1975. This was ferocious indeed and, with the tax cut delayed, recession inevitable (Roberts 1984: 116).
So Reagan and his administration deserve no credit for the fall in inflation rates that occurred in 1981 and 1982. That was the result of Volcker’s policies.
But, as we have seen above, the monetarist doctrine itself that Volcker adopted in 1979 did not even work properly. The Federal Reserve repeatedly missed its M1 targets, despite its quasi-monetarist policy. A deliberately-induced recession is what tamed inflation, and no Keynesian has ever said that high inflation cannot be brought down by causing a severe output and demand contraction, and by throwing millions of people out of work. The “Volcker shock” (as this period is now called) was a vicious and wasteful solution to the double digit inflation of 1979–1981, which inflicted totally unnecessary suffering on the millions of people made unemployed. Moreover, its effect (intended or not) was a savage blow against American manufacturing and working people in those industrial sectors. Another effect of the surge in interest rates was a crisis in the Savings and Loan industry and the push for deregulation in that sector, which culminated in the S&L crisis (see “Reagan Made S&L Crisis Vastly Worse”: William Black Interviewed on The Real News, February 8, 2011). (As an aside, an alternative, Post Keynesian solution to stagflation was incomes policy and, in the long term, commodity buffer stocks; see Musella and Pressman 1999: 1100; Kaldor 1976.)
Moreover, in October 1982, as disaster loomed, the economy was collapsing (and yet to even reach its trough), and Mexico was on the verge of defaulting (which would have bankrupted certain large US banks), Volcker abandoned his quasi-monetarism and returned to a discretionary interest rate policy, through the Federal funds rate (which had always been the main policy instrument before 1979). The Federal funds rate was lowered significantly by the end of 1982.
Years after this disaster, Milton Friedman was interviewed by the Financial Times (7 June 2003). He stated: “The use of quantity of money as a target has not been a success, ... “I’m not sure I would as of today push it as hard as I once did.” Pity it took him 21 years to realise what was obvious to many other people.
In 1981, the “Economic Recovery Tax Act” had already passed Congress on August 4 and signed by Reagan on August 13.
But, as Eichner notes, US fiscal policy under Reagan in fiscal year 1982 was Keynesian, because of automatic stabilizers:
“The reduced tax revenues and the resulting budgetary deficits—at the state and local level as well as at the federal level—nonetheless served to cushion and eventually even to help reverse the cyclical downturn. To this extent, fiscal policy continued to function as an automatic stabilizer” (Eichner 1988: 548).This countercyclical fiscal policy was significantly increased by Reagan’s discretionary spending on defence, and more so by the 1981 tax cut, which increased aggregate demand while government spending was rising. Eichner states:
“The rationale for the 1981 legislation was the “supply-side” argument that a reduction in tax rates would encourage greater savings, leading to a higher rate of capital formation. The savings rate has, however, declined sharply since 1981. Personal savings are currently only 3 percent of disposable income. No less embarrassing for the supply-siders has been the behavior of business investment. While expenditures on new plant and equipment have recovered from their precipitous fall during the recession and have even enjoyed a modest, though brief, boom, the trend growth rate remains unchanged at 3.5 percent” (Eichner 1988: 551–552).So what we in fact had was a supply-side faction in the Reagan administration whose policies, when combined with Reagan’s military spending, provided a Keynesian stimulus to the economy.
“The lower tax rates have not generated more tax revenue as the supply-siders, pointing to the supposed Laffer curve, claimed they would. Indeed, it has been the failure of the lower rates to produce a larger tax yield and the resulting federal budget deficits which, in a more orthodox Keynesian manner, have provided the stimulus for the current economic expansion” (Eichner 1988: 553).
The recovery that began in December 1982 was caused by Volcker’s abandonment of monetarism and lowering of interest rates, automatic stabilizers, military discretionary spending, and tax cuts, which all drove the US budget into deep deficits. This is a standard package of Keynesian stimulus and its major component was countercyclical fiscal policy, though of course of a highly conservative variety. Reagan’s tax cuts favoured the wealthy and significantly increased income inequality in the US. Military spending was wasteful and inferior to social spending and public works.
The victory of military Keynesianism and huge budget deficits in Reagan’s presidency, and his failure to significantly cut total spending, is reflected by the disillusionment of one of the administration’s leading fiscal conservatives, David Stockman, the Director of the Office of Management and Budget from 1981–1985. Stockman resigned in 1985, thinking that the “Reagan Revolution” had failed.
As for Reagan, he continued until 1989, unaware to the end, I bet, that his policy mix after 1982 was unintentional, big-spending conservative Keynesian economics. Hey, big spender.
ADDENDUM: ROTHBARD ON THE SUPPLY-SIDERS
Murray Rothbard wrote a number of attacks on Reagan’s economics from the perspective of Austrian economics. I will quote him on the Supply-Siders:
“The other set of Reaganite deficit-apologists are the Supply-Siders. First, they don’t care about deficits, for they want only tax cuts, and they favor keeping spending levels high. The supply-siders are interventionists and not free-market advocates; they simply want different kinds of intervention. But they agree with liberals and Keynesians that spending levels should be kept high, largely because that is what they think the public wants. Professor Arthur Laffer, in his extreme Laffer Curve variant of supply-side, claims that cuts in tax rates, particularly income-taxes, will almost instantaneously raise tax revenue so much (because of increased work, thrift, and production), that this will achieve a balanced budget painlessly. Like the monetarists, the Lafferites demagogically promise painless economic adjustment; spending levels … can be kept up; tax rates can be sharply cut; and yet we can achieve a balanced budget through a rise in revenues”It is indeed true that the Supply-Siders quickly became apologists for Reagan’s deficits, when tax revenues failed to be boosted significantly by the tax cuts of 1981.
Murray N. Rothbard, “Are We Being Beastly to the Gipper?”
http://www.lewrockwell.com/rothbard/rothbard55.html
Finally, it should be noted that, compared with the very extreme free market Austrians, everyone in their world is an “evil” interventionist – even mainstream Monetarists and Supply-Siders!
PAUL CRAIG ROBERTS ON SUPPLY-SIDE ECONOMICS
I have quoted the Supply-Sider Paul Craig Roberts above. He is worth quoting again on the nature of Supply-side economics:
“The two professional economists who had the first insights into supply-side economics were the University of Chicago trained economist, Norman Ture, and the Canadian economist, Robert Mundell, a Nobel prize-winner in economics ….It seems to me that Supply-Side economics was seen by its supporters as essentially a complement to and correction of the neoclassical Keynesian synthesis.
Supply-side economics corrects a fundamental mistake in Keynesian economics. Most everyone has heard of supply and demand, but Keynesian economics, known as demand management, left out supply ….
Supply-side economics established that fiscal policy shifted the aggregate supply schedule. In his famous economic textbook Nobel economist Paul Samuelson included me and a diagram showing that supply-side economics was an argument that fiscal policy shifted the aggregate supply curve in contrast with the Keynesian emphasis that it shifted the aggregate demand curve. Samuelson declared that the real argument was over the magnitude of the shift.
In other words, the most famous American economist of the 20th century accepted the supply-side theory and said its importance for economic policy depended on its magnitude. Several economists provided empirical evidence of the magnitude, but the disappearance of worsening trade-offs between employment and inflation settled the issue for most.
I myself debated most of the Keynesian Nobel prize-winners before university audiences or before annual meetings of economic associations. When the argument was presented to them, they understood the point and accepted it. I received a standing ovation when I gave the annual State of the Economy address at MIT. The story of how supply-side economics came to be can be found in my book, The Supply-Side Revolution, published by Harvard University Press in 1984.”
Paul Craig Roberts, “What is Supply-Side Economics? Bush Hides Behind Supply-Side to Reward His Cronies,” Counterpunch, February 25 / 26, 2006.
It is surprising that a macroeconomic theory like Supply-Side economics, which shared many traits with the neoclassical synthesis, was so eagerly adopted by anti-government and fiscal conservatives as the basis of a “Reagan revolution.”
Appendix 1: Economic Policy-Makers Under Reagan
White House Chief of Staff
James Baker 1981–1985
Donald Thomas Regan 1985–1987
Chief Domestic Policy Advisor
Martin Anderson 1981–1982
Director of White House Office of Policy Development
Roger B. Porter 1981–1985
Economic Policy Advisory Board
Arthur Laffer 1981–1989
Martin Anderson 1982–1989
Chairs of the Council of Economic Advisers (CEA)
Murray L. Weidenbaum 1981–1982
Martin Feldstein 1982–1984
Beryl W. Sprinkel 1985–1989
Director of the Office of Management and Budget
David Stockman 1981–1985
James C. Miller III 1985–1988
Joseph R. Wright 1988–1989
Chairs of the Federal Reserve
Paul A. Volcker 1979–1987
Alan Greenspan 1987–2006
United States Secretary of the Treasury
Donald Regan 1981–1985
James Baker 1985–1988
Nicholas F. Brady 1988–1993
United States Assistant Secretary of the Treasury for Economic Policy
Paul Craig Roberts 1981–1982
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Eichner, A. S. 1988. “The Reagan Record: A Post Keynesian View,” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 10.4: 541–556.
Galbraith, J. K. 2008. The Predator State: How Conservatives Abandoned the Free Market and Why Liberals Should too, Free Press, New York.
Greider, W. 1981. “The Education of David Stockman,” The Atlantic Online (December), http://www.theatlantic.com/doc/print/198112/david-stockman
Hakes, D. R. and D. C. Rose, 1992–1993. “The 1979-1982 Monetary Policy Experiment: Monetarist, Anti-Monetarist, or Quasi-Monetarist?,” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 15.2: 281–288.
Kaldor, N. 1976. “Inflation and Recession in the World Economy,” Economic Journal 86 (December): 703–714.
Musella, M. and S. Pressman. 1999. “Stagflation,” in P. Anthony O’Hara (ed.), Encyclopedia of Political Economy: L–Z, Routledge, London and New York. 1099–1100.
Roberts, P. C. 1984. The Supply-Side Revolution: An Insider’s Account of Policymaking in Washington, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass. and London.
Schwartz, A. J. 2005. “Aftermath of the Monetarist Clash with the Federal Reserve Before and During the Volcker Era,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 87 (2 Part 2; March/April): 349–351.
Wray, L. R. 2003, “Monetary Policy: An Institutionalist Analysis,” in Marc R. Tool and Paul Dale Bush (eds), Institutional Analysis and Economic Policy, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell, Mass. 85–114.
I distinctly remember a Samuelson quote that roughly said that Friedman was a man of "passion and not science" and that by recommending tax cuts to Reagan, Friedman had (wrongly) hoped to make him reduce spending. I'll just check right now to see if it is right.
ReplyDeleteOf course, this piece highlights that the rise in spending was a deliberate choice of fiscal policy and not a situation of a mere whim by Reagan.
I am astonished, however, by how brief the popularity of Friedman's monetarism was, and how it lasted less longer than his PBS show.
"I am astonished, however, by how brief the popularity of Friedman's monetarism was, and how it lasted less longer than his PBS show."
ReplyDeleteYes, monetarism's 5 minutes of fame happened rather quickly. Central banks have rejected the monetarist idea of targetting the broad money stock or a constant money growth rule.
This is because such control over broad money is impossible in an endogenous money world.
But then why are Messrs. Greenspan and Bernanke called "Monetarists"? Hasn't M1 targetting been abandoned since then? They would not qualify as either orthodox monetarists or quasi-monetarists of Volcker's type.
ReplyDeleteAlso, did you say post-Keynesians advocate incomes policy during stagflation? As in limits on wage and salary rise? The Economist magazine's Norman McRae was an advocate of incomes policy, saying "no incomes policy is too thoughtless". But such measures would be mindboggling to implement. They'd have to monitor and control income from house property, commissions earned, bonuses, dearness allowances, perquisites, retirement benefits, skilled wages, unskilled wages, and so on. I just know they did it during wartime and after, but it seems obvious that they would cease such an arduous task.
“But then why are Messrs. Greenspan and Bernanke called "Monetarists"?”
ReplyDeleteBernanke is a New Keynesian, but appears to agree with Friedman’s explanation of the Great Depression (at least to some extent).
But calling him a “monetarist” in terms of what he normally does at the Fed is highly misleading. Bernanke does NOT conduct monetary policy by using (1) some constant money growth rule or (2) targeting the growth rates of the broad money stock.
These latter two policies are what monetarists want. Bernanke does neither: instead, he uses discretionary changes in interest rates. That is NOT monetarism.
Hasn’t M1 targetting been abandoned since then?
Targeting M1 was abandoned in October 1982, and has never been done since. The Fed tried to target M2 growth rates for the rest of 1980s, but this was also a failure, and the monetarist fiction that the Fed controls broad money was officially abandoned in 1993.
The “New Monetary Consensus” favours discretionary control over interest rates.
“They would not qualify as either orthodox monetarists or quasi-monetarists of Volcker’s type.
You are correct. Neither Greenspan nor Bernanke are monetarists or quasi-monetarists of Volcker’s type.
"Central banks have rejected the monetarist idea of targetting the broad money stock or a constant money growth rule. This is because such control over broad money is impossible in an endogenous money world."
ReplyDeleteCentral banks cannot ignore private banks opinion. After all, private banks offer the most important employment alternative for all previous central banks employees (similarily for economists). Employee career paths of both are often heavily intertwined. And private banks opinion is simple: let us create as much new money as possible and fast, because this is where the historically significantly higher than average profits of private financial institutions come from. Therefore Keynesian perspective was, is and will always be the preferred option in "endogenous money world", ie bankers, financiers and economists. Keynesianism may be summed up in one single advice: subsidize private bankers. Why on earth should then keynesian perspectve be also the preferred perspective of liberals who view private business profits as evil? Beats me.
"Why on earth should then keynesian perspectve be also the preferred perspective of liberals who view private business profits as evil?"
ReplyDeleteThis is a bizzare statment. Liberals do not regard private business profits as "evil".
They suppport private enterprise. American liberalism is not communism.
Perhaps you're thinking of Marxists.
Liberals support private business profits only when they are "socially responsible", otherwise they are harmful. Liberals never accept private business profits as the driver of working class standard of living. This is just marxism light.
ReplyDelete"This is just marxism light."
ReplyDeleteRubbish. Typical of Austrians. All you can do is resort to yelling "communism," "Marxism" etc.
American liberalism has always strongly supported a very large space for free enterprise and production. That is why there was never any serious nationalization of industry in the US after 1945, as opposed to Europe.
The New Deal liberals transformed the US into a mixed economy precisely because they did not want to see America descend into fascism or communism.
Note you have mentioned marxism first. I wouldn't say liberals "support" capitalism, they merely grudgingly accept free enterprise and business profits as unavoidable evils which should be taxed, distributed and forced into "responsibility" before they accrue any profits to society.
ReplyDeleteI found Joanna's post interesting for two reasons.
ReplyDelete1) Social democrats (which is what I think she means by 'liberals') have included a sizable anti-Keynesian group. Social democratic historian Tony Judt, in his last book and political manifesto 'Ill Fares The Land', angrily said that the post-recession shift to Keynesianism in some countries was a "purely tactical retreat". He saw Keynesians as another group of capitalist economists who protect the system. Note also that when Keynesian economist Subramanian Swamy (student of Samuelson) came back to India from MIT in the 1960s, he was angrily condemned as a capitalist extremist by social democratic economists like Amartya Sen in Delhi School of Economics.
2) Keynes himself was a member of the UK Liberal Party (the pro-market party) and even if he greatly differed with other Liberals on issues of trade and fiscal policy, his General Theory was labelled as "conservative in its implications" by the then British press, who perhaps saw it as still too pro-market for its taste. One of the older journalists in The Telegraph in a review for, again, Ill Fares The Land, remarked that even Keynes thought taxes above 25% were too high.
Compared to the utopian ideas of a technocratic paradise, with precise mathematical calculations determining all production and distribution, that were popular among Fabians and pro-nationalisation economists in Britain back in the 1930s, Keynes seems rather modest. Much closer to his friend Hayek than them, if you ask me.
Amartya Sen did his PhD at Cambridge under Joan Robinson, which was then the home of the Cambridge Keynesians who founded Post Keymesianism:
ReplyDeleteTo Sen, then Cambridge was like a battlefield. There were major debates between supporters of Keynesian economics and the diverse contributions of Keynes’ followers, on the one hand, and the “neo-classical” economists skeptical of Keynes, on the other. Sen was lucky to have close relations with economists on both sides of the divide. Meanwhile, thanks to its good “practice” of democratic and tolerant social choice, Sen’s own college, Trinity College, was an oasis very much removed from the discord. However, because of a lack of enthusiasm for social choice theory whether in Trinity or Cambridge, Sen had to choose a quite different subject for his Ph.D. thesis, after completing his B.A. He submitted his thesis on “the choice of techniques” in 1959 under the supervision of the brilliant but vigorously intolerant Joan Robinson."
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Amartya_Sen
Part of the reason he might have "condemned" Subramanian Swamy was that the Keynesianism taught by Samuelson was Neoclassical synthesis Keynesianism, which the Cambridge Keynesians regarded (not unreasonably) as a bastard form of Keynes' thought.
And of course Marxists, Communists, and the varieties thereof think everyone but them is an apologist for capitalism and free markets.
ReplyDeleteMarxists are the ideological reverse of Austrians.
For Austrians everyone except them is an evil apologist for government intervention and socialism. Austrians eagerly await the day that the evil fiat money, interventionist, socialist world will collapse, before the emergence of the free market paradise they imagine will arrive.
Marxists eagerly await the day that the evil capitalist, free market, private profit world will collapse, before the emergence of the socialist paradise they imagine will arrive.
LK, all that "await"ing stuff cannot be further from reality.
ReplyDeleteOn the one hand, Austrians are often influenced by Randian morality (and individualist philosophy in general) which basically posit there should not be free market before massess understand it's good for them (ie pearls should not be cast before swine). So not only they do not await free market paradise, they are ready to actively work against it if massess are liberal/conservative. BTW, that's why there will never be a libertarian revolution (other than, I guess, implausible capitalist strike a la Atlas Shrugged).
On the other hand, one can only wonder who have done all the communist bloody revolutions if Marxians allegedly only "await" capitalist collapse.
"So not only they do not await free market paradise, they are ready to actively work against it if massess are liberal/conservative."
ReplyDelete"Actively work against it if massess are liberal/conservative"??
This is so far from reality, it is astonishing.
Joanna, in fact, they do just await it, and not do anything.
ReplyDeleteLook up some interesting letters on Marxist.Org, such James Burnham's On A Revolutionary Socialist Party. He explains that Bolsheviks never asked for violence, warned their proleteriat protesters against it, but let them go ahead when they would not listen. The idea was that if violence fails, as it did in 1905, then the workers will stop and listen to what the Bolshevik leaders have to suggest. And what they have to suggest is not violence, but a series of tactics to frustrate the bourgeoisie, increase their industrial efficiency and bourgeoisie dependence on them, and effectively hold them hostage as much as possible.
That's not to say Marxists are pacifists - they merely consider violence inefficient. As it is, orthodox Marxists would rather prefer capitalism to be built to its highest industrial efficiency before it falls apart to socialism. Obviously, most Marxists are not orthodox, but you get the idea.
There is a reason Italy never fell to Communism. Communist Italians either stopped or divorced themselves from violent communists, whom they felt were a threat to their communist cause. Stalin would also not support any violent movement in Italy, which would lead to reversal of communism from a backlash.
Look at Egypt, for example. If you see the posts on RevLeft forum, you'll find that several Marxists there don't support the protests, because they feel it is absolutely of no use to the working class, and the instability will do little to raise their wages and productive power. Consistent Marxism is a funny little thing.
In fact, Marxism is so specific, it is not "left wing", it is not "Keynesian", it is not even pro-poor but just pro-worker.
"This is so far from reality, it is astonishing."
ReplyDeleteSure it is, still, there has never been an ideology so commited to individual rights before, up to the point where it at least reveres heroes that work against that very same ideology if that prevents casting pearls before swine. So, libertarians rarely "await" libertarianism, massess should just get what they deserve. Also, note even liberals frequently point out that libertarians are mostly the richer-than-average. Why would libertarians so eagerly "await" libertarianism then? Just to be even richer?
Prateek, yes, there are nuances when you drill down into the theory, but in practice revolution is what's all communists are about.
ReplyDeleteThanks for a very informative analysis. Reagan a Keynesian big spender. Who'da thunk it!
ReplyDeleteFyi, your William Black link now brings up a redirect page that winds up here:
http://neweconomicperspectives.org/2011/02/reagan-made-s-crisis-vastly-worse.html
But the source of the interview being discussed is actually here:
http://www.therealnews.com/t2/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=31&Itemid=74&jumival=6233
Again, thanks for all the work you put into this. Very helpful to know there's what the pundits and commentators say about Reagan, and then there's what actually goes on in the real world!